Why has it taken so long to restore solid economic growth in
America? Why have so many American families
lost their jobs, their incomes – even their homes? A key reason may well be the overvalued U.S. dollar
and the External Deficit Doom Loop.
No one really noticed the doom loop developing, but over the
past 40 years, the American economy became trapped in a downward spiral driven
by an overvalued dollar and rising trade deficits. As shown in the graphic
below, the external deficit doom loop touches every sector of the economy.
Let’s
see how problems at each stage have become linked to form a job-destroying, growth-destroying
doom loop.
1. Exchange Rate Rises.
2. External Deficit Increases.
The overvalued dollar makes U.S. exports too expensive and
foreign imports too cheap. This kills both domestic and foreign demand for U.S.
products. The inevitable result: destructively high trade deficits.
3. Foreign Capital Inflows Increase. To cover the deficit and to
invest or speculate in America ’s
exuberant financial markets, more foreign capital comes in, pushing the dollar
ever-higher.
4. Portfolio and Direct Investment Distorted. Especially during periods of high
trade deficits, the share of foreign capital inflows for productive direct
investment falls, reducing the real direct investment that would otherwise make
it easier for American companies to compete. In fact, increased portfolio flows are a key reason that external deficits create even worse external deficits.
5. Money and Inflation Rise. Capital inflows from abroad,
particularly the rising share entering as portfolio rather than direct
investment inflows, work like high-powered money. With fractional reserve
banking, portfolio flows expand credit, leading to inflation that further
overvalues the dollar in real, price-adjusted terms. Inflation further reduces the
ability of U.S.
manufacturers to compete with foreign products, both at home and abroad.
6. Business Profits Fall. Faced with increasing competition from
underpriced foreign products in both domestic and foreign markets, manufacturing
plants and other businesses producing internationally traded goods see demand
drop. Their output, revenues and profits all fall accordingly.
7. Productivity Growth Declines. Falling
profits reduce the capacity and incentives for companies to make the
investments in R&D, equipment and workforce training needed to improve
productivity.
8. Jobs and Personal Incomes Fall. With jobs being offshored
and plants closing, the economy slows – and may even go into a recession, raising
unemployment levels. In addition to personal hardship, this means less demand
for domestically produced goods, putting further pressure on domestic producers
already facing a shortfall in foreign demand because of the overvalued dollar.
9. Government Revenues Fall and Expenditures Rise. As the
growth of personal incomes and business profits slows or goes into reverse,
government revenues suffer. Simultaneously, the government comes under
increasing pressure to provide income support for poor families, bailouts for
failing corporations, and economic stimulus programs. Budget deficits balloon.
10. Government Foreign Borrowing Increases. Larger budgets mean
more borrowing, and between the foreign investors’ appetite for Treasuries and the
U.S. Treasury’s appetite for cheap money, the sale of U.S. government debt to
foreign countries grows dramatically – think currency manipulation.
How to Escape the External Deficit Doom Loop
Implement a Trade Balancing Market
Access Charge (MAC)
America does not need to suffer through yet another recession-generating,
job-killing external deficit doom loop. Such a disaster can be prevented by
removing the prime driver of this doom loop – the excessive foreign capital inflows
that push the dollar’s value to uncompetitive levels.
Foreign capital inflows should never be stopped. They have a
tremendous potential to benefit American growth – just as outflows of capital
from America
can benefit growth in other countries. But policies must be put into place to
moderate capital inflows so that they are consistent with the real needs of the
American economy. With a fairly competitive dollar, one that generates neither
deficits nor surpluses, Americans once again would be able to earn as much
producing exports as they spend on imports.
Capital inflows could easily be moderated with a Market
Access Charge (MAC). With a MAC, whenever the United States had trade deficits
exceeding one percent of GDP on average for the past year, a MAC, initially set
at 50 basis points (one-half percent), would be collected on all capital coming
into the United States, regardless of source, channel, or claimed purpose.
Even such a low charge would significantly slow short-term speculative
portfolio inflows, but would have no negative impact on serious long-term
inflows of productive direct investment capital. In fact, by creating a more
competitive dollar, the MAC would increase the profitability of manufacturing in
America, making foreign direct investment here even more attractive.
The MAC would rise in increments proportional to the
increase in the external deficit. For example, if the deficit increased by 1 percentage point from
1% to 2% of GDP, the MAC could be increased by one percentage point or 100 basis points.
This would continue until the capital flows had moderated to the point that the
dollar was becoming more competitive as indicated by a falling external trade
deficit. As the deficit declined, so would the MAC. When the deficit dropped
below one percent of GDP, the charge would drop to zero.
The MAC would be transparent, targeted, temporary, and
non-discriminatory, making it consistent with the new IMF guidelines for
capital flow management policies. The charge would be deducted electronically
from all foreign capital inflow transactions and be transferred to the U.S. Treasury.
The U.S. Government could use MAC revenues to encourage exports, stimulate the
creation of new small businesses and new jobs, and offset any increased costs
of U.S. government borrowing. With a MAC in place, government borrowing would come
increasingly from domestic sources. This would reduce the sale of U.S.
Treasuries to countries like Japan
and China ,
depriving them of their instrument of choice for manipulating the U.S. dollar’s
exchange rate. The MAC would also raise U.S. savings rates and help protect
retirees and others depending on fixed income investments.
With a competitive dollar, Americans would earn as much
producing exports as they spend on imports. Rising foreign and domestic demand
for their products would make U.S. businesses more profitable, leading them to
hire more workers, raise wages, and invest in productivity. Higher profits and
family incomes would increase government revenues and reduce government
expenditures, reducing both the budget deficit and America’s mountain of public
debt (currently about 100% of GDP). In short, implementing a Market Access
Charge would restore a rock-solid foundation for America’s future. America
needs a fairly competitive dollar now.
John
Hansen, PhD
America Needs a Competitive Dollar - Now!
No comments :
Post a Comment
What do you think? Join the Conversation