Summary
Understanding the impact of trade deficits and foreign debt on
economic growth is vital to understanding the origins of America’s current economic
problems and to designing trade and monetary policies that will put America
back on the path to prosperity for all in the 21st century.
Unfortunately,
economists are sharply divided regarding the impact of trade imbalances on
growth.
Progressive economists such as Scott
and Baker
generally say that trade deficits are the leading cause of slow growth, excessive
unemployment and growing social inequality in the United States, that trade
deficits threaten the nation’s long-term economic viability.
In sharp contrast,
conservative economists such as Riley,
Griswold
and Ikenson
would generally say that trade deficits mean faster economic growth and falling
unemployment, that the foreign loans used to finance these deficits are an
important vote of confidence in America.
The 2015
Economic Report of the President by the Council of Economic Advisors
presents both of these conflicting positions but fails to reconcile them or to
provide meaningful policy options for action.
This note reconciles the conservative and progressive views
and presents a possible consensus position on U.S. trade policy for the 21st
Century, one that could simultaneously increase business profitability, stimulate
innovation, maximize employment, and reduce income inequality.
Implementing a
policy along the lines outlined here would also reduce Government deficits
while enabling Government to focus more squarely on providing the foundations
for solid economic growth that is shared by all.
Conservative Arguments why Trade Deficits are Good
Conservatives, who
have a fundamental faith that unfettered markets are the best way to produce
good economic and social results, commonly argue that America should welcome rather
than discourage trade deficits. They generally show little concern that free
trade agreements may well lead to larger U.S. trade deficits with the countries
involved and to lower shares of manufacturing in total U.S. employment.
Conservatives support their positive view of trade deficits with
charts that show higher trade deficits and higher economic growth rising and falling
hand-in-hand (Fig. 1).
From 1970-1980, trade deficits were relatively small, so no
clear relationship emerged between them and GDP growth. Starting in 1980,
however, two very clear patterns began to emerge, patterns that demonstrate why
the conservatives are right that GDP and trade deficits have tended to rise
together, and why progressives are right that trade deficits hurt GDP growth.
How can such contradictory conclusions both be true? The answer is quite simple. As with so many
economic phenomena, conclusions depend heavily on perspective. Here the key issue is whether one takes a
short-term or a long-term view.
The conservatives point to the strong positive correlation
between GDP growth and trade deficits over specific short-term periods such as
the following cycles: [i]
- 1982 - 1993: Growth and trade deficits went up as the
second oil crisis faded and the stimulus of the Plaza Accord kicked in,
and they headed down with the Crash of 1987 and the following recession.
- 1995 - 2005: During the tech bubble, both indicators
rose markedly, peaking around the year 2000, at which point the tech
bubble burst. Reasonably parallel growth in the two indicators then
resumed with the housing and stock market, peaking about 2005.
- 2005 - 2008. Growth and
trade deficits fell with the collapse of the housing and stock market
bubbles, hitting bottom about 2009.
- 2009 – Present: Growth rose
slowly following the Great Recession, stimulated by natural recovery,
fiscal and monetary stimulus, and a temporarily more competitive dollar. The
trade deficit declined, reflecting lower aggregate demand as U.S.
companies and households tightened their belts, borrowing and consuming
less in order to “restructure their balance sheets” and get out from under
the debts that had piled up during the mid-2000s housing and consumption
boom.
Although the fit is far from exact for the individual
boom-bust cycles, the data generally support the conservative view that higher
trade deficits are often associated with higher rates of economic growth – and
vice versa – at least during certain relatively short-term periods.
Before going on to the reasons that Figure 1 also supports
the progressive view that trade deficits are bad for economic growth and employment,
let’s look more closely at the short-term linkages between trade deficits and accelerated
growth.
When the U.S. imports more than it exports, it can cover the
deficits in various ways:
- First, since the U.S. has
the right to pay most of its trade deficits in U.S. dollars, the U.S. could
simply print the needed dollars. However, this could easily lead to
domestic inflation and to the world’s losing confidence in American dollars.
- Second, the U.S. could draw
down its foreign exchange reserves which, by definition, must be in
convertible currencies other than U.S. dollars. However, since America can
print its own convertible currency, its official reserves of foreign currency
are very small.
- Third, the U.S. can borrow
money from abroad, using credits from foreign governments and private
investors to cover trade deficits. And this is exactly what it does.
Herein lies the reason that GDP growth cycles have tended
over the past 30-40 years to move in tandem with trade deficit cycles. Additional
credit (and debt) flowing into the United States to cover the deficits means
that America can temporarily live beyond its means, spending more on consumption
and investment than it produces as GDP. When domestic expenditure exceed domestic
production, this stimulates economic growth and employment.
These clear logical linkages between trade deficits and
economic growth indicate that the conservative side may indeed be right.
But wait. There is a dark side to this strategy that explains
why the progressive view is also right—that trade deficits can be very harmful
to economic growth and to employment over the longer term.
Given that America has had an almost unbroken string of
trade deficits for some forty years, we clearly need to look at the long-term
implications of these deficits before deciding on a national trade policy for
the 21st century.
Progressive Arguments why Trade Deficits are Bad
We all know that allowing debts to mount up year after year will
almost certainly end badly. Families have a limit; so do countries. The U.S.
has clearly not reached that limit as a country, but as indicated in Fig. 2, it
has clearly been moving in that direction.
Prior to the late 1980s, America was the world’s largest
creditor (including both equity and portfolio investments). Since then, however,
its liabilities to the rest of the world have increased far more rapidly than
its assets. This has increased sharply the ratio of net foreign liabilities to
GDP, making America’s “net international investment position” (NIIP) ever more
negative.
As worrisome as the message of Figure 2 may be, the reality of
the impact of trade deficits on America’s economy and society should be of even
greater concern. Let’s return to Fig. 1,
which at first glance seems to support the conservative position that trade
deficits and the associated foreign financing flows stimulate growth and
employment.
This time, look not at the rough parallels between the ups
and downs of GDP growth and trade deficits. Look instead at the dotted lines
which show the average 40-year trends in trade deficits and GDP growth. This reveals
a totally different picture.
Over the long term, rather than stimulating economic growth,
growing trade deficits have been associated with falling GDP growth. During
the 1970s, trade deficits averaged only 0.2% of GDP, while GDP growth averaged
3.2% per year. In contrast, between 2000 and 2013, average trade deficits shot
up to 4.1% of GDP while growth slowed to less than 2 percent per year. In short, over the past 40 years, higher
trade deficits have meant a sharp reduction in average growth, not an increase
as some conservative economists might suggest.
As with any statistical analysis, it is vitally important to
show not only mathematical correlations between raw numbers, but also to look
for reasons why variables might be positively
or negatively correlated.
The above analysis of the conservative position suggests
that injections of credit to finance trade deficits explain why, over
relatively short time periods, GDP and trade deficits would tend to expand in parallel.
But why would this short-term relationship flip in the longer term? Why after some point should more foreign debt
have a negative rather than a positive impact on economic growth and
employment?
The Misuse of National Accounts Identities
The traditional explanation given by economists,
particularly the more liberal ones, is that the standard national accounts
equation shows that there is a mathematical link between higher trade deficits
and lower GDP growth:
GDP = Consumption + Investment + Exports – Imports (a)
Since imports appear on the right-hand side with a negative
sign, increasing imports must reduce GDP, all other things remaining equal –
or at least so it would appear.
However, this logic is flawed and leads to bad policy
conclusions. As Riley has rightly noted, this formulation makes it appear as
though “exports add to GDP and
imports subtract.” He goes on to say that, if this were true, “Americans would
be richer if the Navy torpedoed ships loaded with products before they could
reach U.S. ports.”
Using the standard
national accounts formula when analyzing the links between trade deficits and GDP growth is wrong because, in addition to
implying a mechanical linkage that does not exist, it confuses GDP as
production with GDP as expenditure, and it examines GDP at a point in time
rather than as a dynamic process over time.
For analyzing
links between trade deficits and economic growth,
we have to focus on the production of GDP over time – on the growth of
total value added by all sectors in the economy such as agriculture,
mining, energy, manufacturing, and transportation.
Equation (a), however,
refers only to the expenditure of GDP on
consumption and investment at a given point in time – a totally
different concept than the production
of GDP over time. Equation (a) only
says that, if a country spends more on consumption plus investment than it
produces, it will import more than it exports, which by extension means that it
may well to borrow to cover the difference. A more useful presentation of
equation (a) would be:
GDX = GDP + Imports - Exports (b),
where GDX is gross
domestic expenditure (consumption plus investment). This formulation makes it
clear that it is gross domestic expenditure, not gross domestic product, that increases
as the gap between imports and exports rises.
The External Deficit Doom Loop – the real reason trade deficits hurt
long-run economic growth
The reason that
persistent trade deficits will almost certainly reduce rather than increase GDP
growth and employment can be summarized with this simple example: If America
borrows money from China to pay China to produce goods that could be produced competitively
in America, America’s economy will produce less, GDP will grow more slowly, and
unemployment will be higher.
America has gotten
itself into this unfortunate situation largely because of what might be called
an External Deficit Doom Loop (EDDL).
The EDDL is an ongoing process with neither
beginning nor end, one that affects virtually all aspects of the American economy
and society. However, our story must
start somewhere, so given that the exchange rate determines the relative prices
and thus the competitiveness of all American
goods and services (including wages) compared to foreign goods and services, let’s
start with the overvaluation of the dollar[ii]
that began in the mid-1970s following the first oil crisis (see the first step
in the presentation of the external deficit doom loop in Figure 3.)[iii]
1. Exchange Rate
Overvaluation. Rather
than implementing policies that would allow the dollar to move to levels that
would balance its external trade despite sharply higher oil prices, America
understandably and to a considerable degree justifiably chose to borrow to
cover the resulting trade deficits.[iv]
Interestingly, most of the money was borrowed from the very countries that were
enjoying large trade surpluses with America because they had raised oil prices
as members of the OPEC cartel. The parallels between the OPEC money flowing
into the U.S. during the oil crises and the Chinese money flowing into the
United States starting in the late 1990s are painfully clear.
2. Trade Deficits. Sharply higher oil prices, combined with
high rates of inflation in the United States, led directly to a substantial
overvaluation of the dollar. This in turn led to rising trade deficits, not
only with the OPEC countries, but with others as well. In 1972, America
experienced its first trade deficit in nearly 100 years (the last one occurring
during Reconstruction after the Civil War), and with the exceptions of very
small surpluses in 1973 and 1975, America has had trade deficits every year
since 1972 (see Figure 1).
3. Foreign Capital Inflows. The next step in the doom loop that has
trapped the American economy is the inflow of foreign capital to cover the
external deficits. Although conservatives tend to regard such foreign capital
inflows as “good news” for the economy. When foreign direct investment brings
not only capital but access to technology and markets that U.S. firms do not
already have, it can indeed be good news.
However, when foreign direct
investment simply means that China use America’s trade deficit dollars to buy
America’s productive assets such as happened with its purchase of the pig farms
owned by Smithfield, America is simply paying the price of living beyond its
means, squandering its real assets on excessive consumption of foreign goods.
Warren Buffett’s comments in his 2003 Fortune magazine article about “Thriftville” and “Squanderville”
immediately come to mind. Foreign capital inflows can lead to other highly
unfavorable developments for reasons that will become clear as we continue
around the loop.
4. Shift from Productive
Investments to Hot Money. One
common development rarely noted regarding international capital flows is that
the composition of these flows changes rather dramatically depending on whether
the country is running significant trade deficits or surpluses.
For China, which
has long enjoyed substantial trade surpluses, capital flows are dominated by
direct investments in factories and other directly productive projects. Over
the same period, however, the United States has seen substantial trade deficits,
and foreign capital inflows have generally gone into portfolio investments and loans.
This pattern reflects the fact that, almost by definition, production in
deficit countries is less competitive and thus less profitable than in
countries with trade surpluses. The dominance of portfolio and loan-based flows
over direct investments has three potentially negative consequences.
First, unlike
direct investments where future capital outflows depend largely on the
profitability of the investment portfolio, loans involve contractual repayment
obligations that must be met regardless of the profitability of the investment.
Second, portfolio
investments and outright loans tend to be more short-term and speculative. Funds
not tied to specific physical investments can easily become “hot money,” fleeing
at the first signs of trouble.
Third, when the
foreign loans are used primarily to finance consumption of imported goods
rather than productive investments, they generate no direct benefits that can
be used to help meet repayment obligations.
Incidentally, the
impact of trade deficits on the composition of foreign capital inflows is by no
means unique to the United States. Similar patterns can be seen, for example, in
the Asian Crisis of 1997, and in the ongoing Eurozone crisis where portfolio
investments and loans flooded into countries like Greece, Spain, Italy and
Portugal from financial institutions in countries like Germany and France.
5. Money, Credit, Inflation
and Financial Market Volatility. One
of the most damaging links in the external deficit doom loop is the impact that
the inflow of foreign credit has on domestic inflation and financial sector
stability. The damage is perhaps seen most vividly in the case of government
borrowing from abroad to finance budget deficits.
When the U.S. Government,
for example, borrows funds domestically, this simply shifts purchasing power
from private to public hands within America.
Such borrowing may “crowd out” more productive private sector uses of the
funds, but domestic borrowing per se does
not generate a net increase in domestic purchasing power. Consequently, such
borrowing has a limited impact on domestic inflation, and thus on the cost of
producing U.S. exports.
In contrast, when
the Government borrows more from abroad than it repays, total purchasing power
circulating within the economy increases immediately by the amount of net
borrowing. In the early 1970s, foreign borrowing by the Federal Government
accounted for only about five percent of total government borrowing.
However,
since about 2007, government borrowing from foreign sources has accounted for
45-50 percent of the stock of total publicly-held government debt– and has
equaled 30-35 percent of GDP, representing a significant percentage increase in
the amount of money circulating in the economy and thus to inflationary
pressures.
Even if this were
the end of the story, the implications for the international competitiveness of
U.S. manufacturing would be highly negative in the absence of compensating
changes in the exchange rate. But this is not
the end of the story.
When the
government increases its net borrowing from China by $100 billion, for example,
most if not all of this money immediately goes to pay employees, contractors,
and suppliers. Most people receiving the
money will immediately deposit it in banks. Under America’s fractional reserve banking
system, the banks can then lend out roughly $90 of every $100 deposited,
holding back only about 10 percent as mandatory reserves.
If the
deposit-and-relend process were to continue until no further loans could be
made given reserve requirements, the original $100 billion dollars would grow
to about $1.0 trillion of additional money in circulation. In fact, using
rather conservative assumptions, it can be shown that the majority of the
credit expansion that has taken place over the past 10 years could be explained
by the expansion of credit based on net borrowing from abroad.
The negative
significance of the dramatic expansion of credit in the American economy
relative to GDP can hardly be overemphasized.
Between 1950 and
1970, for example, total credit market debt in the United States fluctuated in
a narrow range, averaging about 150 percent of GDP (Fig. 4). But this changed dramatically between the
mid-1970s and the mid-1980s – precisely the period when America began to run
external trade deficits almost every year.
Within about 10 years, the ratio of credit market debt to GDP rose from the long-term average of 150 percent to 200 percent. Then, between 1985 and 2008, just before the house of credit cards collapsed and America fell into the Great Recession, the ratio of credit to GDP exploded from 200% to over 350%.
Within about 10 years, the ratio of credit market debt to GDP rose from the long-term average of 150 percent to 200 percent. Then, between 1985 and 2008, just before the house of credit cards collapsed and America fell into the Great Recession, the ratio of credit to GDP exploded from 200% to over 350%.
By this point
America – and most of the developed world – was deeply addicted to the debt.
Like the meth or crack addict who constantly needs an ever-larger hit just to
avoid depression and to function “normally,” the world economy in general and
the American economy in particular became addicted to debt. Unfortunately,
America has become the lead addict on behalf of the world. Although America has
frequently been referred to as the world’s “engine of growth,” in reality it is
the consumer of last resort for the world’s excess of production over domestic
demand. To fulfill this role, America has become the world’s borrower of last
resort and the world’s largest debtor.
If the growing
mountain of credit and debt within the United States had actually increased the
overall rate of economic growth, we could probably say that this was a healthy
development. However, as was seen in Fig. 1, average GDP growth has
actually been falling.
The amount of credit required to produce a dollar of GDP more than doubled between 1970 and 2008, indicating a dramatic decline in the efficiency of the financial sector.[v] The fact that the increasingly large “hits” of credit being injected into the American economy have had increasingly less impact on America’s economic growth is a clear sign that America is like a crack addict when it comes to debt.
The amount of credit required to produce a dollar of GDP more than doubled between 1970 and 2008, indicating a dramatic decline in the efficiency of the financial sector.[v] The fact that the increasingly large “hits” of credit being injected into the American economy have had increasingly less impact on America’s economic growth is a clear sign that America is like a crack addict when it comes to debt.
The other big
problem with America’s addiction to foreign capital inflows is that, both
directly and through the money multiplier effects of fractional reserve
banking, foreign capital inflows have increased the risk of financial
instability, particularly the risk, as Kindleberger once noted, of “manias,
panics, and crashes.”
Financial manias,
which are almost always preceded by a sharp increase in credit, can be very
exciting for investors. Consequently, no one, including otherwise intelligent
bankers and Federal Reserve officials, wants to take away the punch bowl of
excessive credit. As Chuck Prince of Citigroup famously said about the time of
the 2008 Crash, “… as long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and
dance. We’re still dancing.”
Today we know the
hangover was not worth the party. We are still paying for the excesses of that
wild journey into darkness – a journey financed in large measure by the surge
of foreign capital into America during a string of notorious bubbles that our
policy makers did not want to burst. To avoid a repeat of that disaster, we
must learn from it. Only by doing so can we avoid another trip around the external
deficit doom loop and into the pit of financial excess.
6. Business Profits Fall. Once the EDDL was in full swing, the rapid
growth of credit-fueled domestic inflation in America relative to the rest of
the world eroded the international competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing
companies. Their profitability fell – far more rapidly than might be expected.
Assume, for example, that the real value of the dollar has fallen by 10 percent
because of a 10 percent increase in domestic price levels.
However, if the
nominal exchange rate does not fall by a comparable amount, thereby offsetting
the 10 percent increase in domestic prices over world prices, manufacturers who
could previously sell a product for $100 and make a profit of $10 would have to
cut their price by about 10 percent to $90 – at which point, not 10 percent but
100 percent of their profits would disappear! [vi]
Many manufacturers
today in America have profit margins on value of output considerably smaller than
10 percent, and for them, the 10 percent “tax” imposed by the overvalued dollar
can turn a profitable business into a loss-maker. Furthermore, the overvalued
dollar “tax” also affects domestic producers who sell only in the domestic
market. For example, if a Chinese producer can profitably deliver a shirt to
the U.S. market for $10, a domestic shirt producer who can’t meet this “China
price” will not be able to sell his shirts, even within America.
Businesses today
complain loudly about the severe burden imposed by the 35 percent corporate
income tax rate. However, the CIT only takes 35 percent of the profit actually earned. If the profit is zero,
the tax is zero. In contrast, the overvalued dollar tax today takes about 15
percent of the selling price, not the
profit actually made – even if the profit is already zero.
7. Productivity Growth
Declines. Some argue
that the eclipse of American manufacturing by other countries like China is
driven by the fact that America is not investing enough in R&D. America does fall seriously short in this
area, but what sane business person would invest in plant, equipment, training,
and R&D when, even with a world-class operation, the overvalued dollar
makes it impossible to compete effectively in domestic markets against imports,
much less with exports to world markets? The overvalued dollar will have to be
fixed before America sees major new investments in the manufacturing sector.
8. Jobs and Income. As the profits of America’s manufacturing
sector fall, plants begin laying off workers, moving production overseas, and
even closing plants entirely. Unemployment rises while wages and family incomes
fall, exacerbating income inequality and reducing aggregate demand for the
output of American factories. This, combined with the falling demand for new
capital equipment and for American exports, creates another vicious cycle of
declining demand, declining GDP, and rising unemployment.
9. Government Revenues,
Expenditures and Deficits. The
Government plays a critically important role in the external deficit doom loop,
both as victim and as villain. As victim, the Government suffers in two ways.
First, as economic growth declines, both personal and business income growth
rates decline or may even become negative. This reduces the tax base and thus Government
revenues. Second, with rising rates of business failure and joblessness, the Government
faces increased demand for bailouts for businesses and for income support
programs for individuals, increasing government expenditures. The combination
of falling revenues and rising expenditures quickly produces rising government
deficits – a trend seen clearly following the Crash of 2008.
10. Government Foreign
Borrowing. Rising budget
deficits quickly turn the Government into a villain in the EDDL story. In the
1970s, only about five percent of all government debt was held by foreign
buyers (Fig. 5). Consequently, the impact of government debt on total
credit in the U.S. economy was minimal.
However, as noted above, the share of government debt rose dramatically during the 1970s with petro-dollar recycling. By the end of the decade, about 20 percent of U.S. Government debt was held by foreigners. The share stabilized at this level until the Tech Bubble began in the mid-1990s.
However, as noted above, the share of government debt rose dramatically during the 1970s with petro-dollar recycling. By the end of the decade, about 20 percent of U.S. Government debt was held by foreigners. The share stabilized at this level until the Tech Bubble began in the mid-1990s.
Within about five
short years between then and the Tech Wreck, the share of U.S. Government debt held
by foreign lenders rose from 20 to 35 percent.
The Government’s dependency on foreign lenders
dropped to about 30 percent with Y2K and with the end of the Tech Boom.
However, China’s trade surpluses with the United States began to explode during
the mid-2000s and Japan’s trade surpluses with America remained sizeable.
Consequently, China and Japan became major buyers of U.S. Government
securities. This had several important consequences:
- First, the share of publicly held U.S. Government
securities owed to foreigners rose to nearly 50 percent, an unprecedented
level for the United States, and the share has remained between 45 percent
and 50 percent since then despite the Crash of 2008.
- Second, the flood of money from abroad, most of which was
financed by America’s burgeoning trade deficits with China and Japan, led
to the explosion of credit within the United States that fed directly into
the housing and stock market booms that preceded the Crash of 2008.
- Third, the money coming into the United States seeking to
buy dollars and dollar-based assets for return and safety has kept the
value of the U.S. dollar above the level that would balance imports and
exports.
This sets off the next round of the external deficit doom
loop. If domestic prices in America have increased more rapidly than prices in
key trading partner countries during the previous EDDL loop, the exchange rate
will be more overvalued than before in
real (price-adjusted) terms because of excessive credit circulating
domestically, the result of excessive foreign capital inflows. And in nominal terms, the market exchange rate
will be more overvalued if investors have brought more foreign capital into the
United States to purchase dollars and dollar-based assets than was needed
simply to cover existing trade deficits.
With the dollar ever-more overvalued in both nominal and real terms, imports will be “too
cheap,” U.S. exports “too expensive,” and the trade deficit will again reach
new heights, driving another cycle of the external deficit doom loop that has
already taken place far too often since the 1970s.
Policy Conclusions and Recommendations
Even though conservative economists argue that trade
deficits and economic growth generally seem to rise together, while progressive
economists argue that trade deficits are bad for growth and bad for employment,
this paper finds that both sides are right.
The two positions are consistent with each other because, in
the short term, trade deficits and the associated financing inflows do have a
stimulative impact on the economy, but in the longer term, trade deficits
clearly harm domestic economic growth and employment.[vii]
This finding holds the promise of providing a basis for a
consensus on American trade policy for the 21st century. Regardless
of our individual positions along the political spectrum, we all agree that the
present and future well-being of our country and its people is the top
priority.
From America’s experience
over the past forty years, it is obvious that trade deficits, excessive foreign
capital dependency, excessive domestic credit, repeated financial crises,
slowing economic growth, excessive unemployment, large budget deficits, and
increased long-term indebtedness to foreign countries, many of whom are far
more concerned about their own welfare than they are about ours, is a dead-end
road.
America has become addicted to debt, both domestic and
foreign. In small doses over limited periods of time, debt can be good for
economic growth. But over longer periods, debt dependency depresses economic
growth and could ultimately endanger America’s strength and sovereignty.
We all would agree, I believe, that any policies implemented
should give top priority to America’s international strategic, political,
economic and social strength – subject only to the caveat that our actions
as a nation contribute to a level global playing field and do not seek to harm
the people of other nations.
The world’s global trading system has done wonders for
people around the world, lifting millions if not billions out of poverty.
Expanded global trade has also given those in developed countries like the
United States sharply improved access at lower cost to some of the finest goods
and services ever available.
At the same time, however, cross-border financial flows have
grown far more rapidly than the flows of real goods and services – a clear
reflection that the global financial sector is becoming addicted to casino-type
speculation rather than to intermediating at the lowest possible cost between
those who have capital to invest and those who need capital to produce real
goods and services.[viii]
Given the obvious damage that excessive financial flows have
done in terms of generating speculative financial crises such as the Crash of
2008, the dismal aftermath of such crises such as the Great Recession, and the
undeniably negative impact of excessive trade deficits on domestic economic
growth and employment, it seems fair to suggest that a core element in America’s
trade policy for the 21st century should be a mechanism that would
moderate these flows, keeping them at levels consistent with balanced trade in
real goods and services.
This goal could
easily be attained as outlined elsewhere in this blog (see post of May 1: Balance U.S. Trade with a MAC Attack on Currency Misalignment).
American Needs a Competitive Dollar-Now!
-----------------------------------------------------------------------
[i] These ranges must be interpreted with caution for two reasons: First, the data
are three-year trailing averages; the data point plotted for 2008, for example,
is actually the average for 2006-2008. Second, cycles in trade deficits and GDP
growth rarely coincide exactly because they are driven in different ways by
factors that are often not highly correlated.
[ii] An “overvalued” currency is one that results in an excess of imports over exports, resulting in trade deficits that are both sustained and significant.
[iii] Although the EDDL is presented here as a circular process, this is strictly a presentational simplification. In reality, all points connect to all points on the circle. The EDDL is really a network of interactions, not a simple circle.
[iv] The decision not to balance external trade with a substantial devaluation of
the dollar during the OPEC oil crisis was understandable because a sharp
devaluation would have been highly unpopular with the American public and
justifiable to the extent that a substantial devaluation could have triggered a
sharp recession or even a depression, the cost of which would have
significantly exceeded the cost of borrowing from abroad to cover the deficits.
[v] The only economic reason for having a financial sector is to bring savers and
spenders together at the lowest possible cost. The massive computerization of
America’s financial sector should have resulted in a dramatic decline in the
share of GDP needed to intermediate between savers and spenders -- between
creditors and debtors. However, precisely the opposite is true. Maintaining the
financial sector required only 3.6 percent of GDP in 1950, but by 2014, this
share had nearly doubled to about 6.3 percent of GDP. A key reason for this
growing inefficiency of the financial sector is the dramatic increase in the
share of loans made by financial institutions to other financial institutions,
and the dramatic decline in the share of total loans made to non-financial
institutions – the businesses who actually produce goods and services for
intermediate and final consumption for sale in domestic and international
markets.
[vi] The calculations here obviously depend on many other assumptions regarding
developments in other markets, but the basic message is clear.
[vii] National and global conditions have a tremendous impact on the speed with which the depressive effects of the external deficit doom loop overwhelm the short-term stimulative effects of trade deficits and external financing. Furthermore, national and global conditions change over time, which helps explain the significant disconnects in Figure 1 over time between trade deficits and economic growth. Given the variance and unpredictability of the factors driving the short-term and long-term effects, it would be irresponsible to claim that a bright line separates short-term and long-term effects.
[viii] The rising dominance of financial over real flows is seen in two particularly relevant indicators. First, according to data from the Bank for International Settlements, enough foreign exchange to finance the entire annual U.S. trade deficit flowed across U.S. borders in 2013 in less than half of one day, and enough flowed across our borders in four days to finance all U.S. imports and exports for an entire year. Second, between 1975 and 2009, for example, world trade increased by about 15-fold, but global foreign exchange reserves grew by almost 45 times – three times faster than global trade. Why did this happen despite the fact that computerization of global financial flows over this period should have reduced the need for such flows sharply?
No comments :
Post a Comment
What do you think? Join the Conversation